Beto vs. Liz Warren 2020 Democratic Debate: at odds on breaking up tech giants like Amazon

We finally have an important debate on big tech in the Democratic Party

Published April 21, 2019 4:29PM (EDT)

Sen. Elizabeth Warren, D-MA (AP/Frank Franklin II)
Sen. Elizabeth Warren, D-MA (AP/Frank Franklin II)

This article was produced by Economy for All, a project of the Independent Media Institute.

Senator Elizabeth Warren made national headlines with her recently released plans to break up tech giants Amazon, Google, Facebook, and Apple, making it one of her signature proposals as she campaigns for the presidency. She is not alone. But now we have the first stirrings of an intra-party debate on the subject: Beto O’Rourke has explicitly opposed the Warren proposal to break up Amazon, arguing that “it is not the proper route to pursue ‘to ensure dynamism in our economy,’” according to a recent Business Insider report by Joe Perticone. Although he doesn’t cite other companies, the “economic dynamism” argument would presumably apply to other big tech companies, as far as O’Rourke goes, although he has not yet fleshed out further metrics to make his case.

There’s no question that Senator Warren’s idea resonates in our political memory—Teddy Roosevelt made his name as the trust-buster, for going after the great monopolies of the early 20th century in the name of the public interest. Twenty-first-century populist economics in America continues to be adorned the century-old piece of political syntax, “break ’em up.” But would breaking up the big tech giants actually reduce the dynamism of the American economy, as O’Rourke suggests?

Warren’s essential rationale is that these tech companies act as monopolies and need to be cut down in size in order to promote more competitive markets, via traditional antitrust instruments such as the Sherman Act. Furthermore, as legal scholar Kelsey Mullane highlights, Warren is also advocating “new legislation that would regulate large tech platforms and the appointment of federal regulators who will enforce our antitrust laws and retroactively terminate anti-competitive mergers.” The premise is that increased competition via vigorous antitrust activity and more regulatory activism will act as a spur to additional innovation, as it levels the playing field between large and small businesses.

Here is an even bigger goal implicit in Warren’s call for an ambitious exercise of antitrust law. She wants to use it to address other social friction points, notably improving the quality of employment, mitigating wealth inequality, better protecting data privacy and enhancing national security. In short, her policies reflect an expansion of antitrust policy away from the narrow focus of the so-called “Chicago School” (which largely uses the metrics of economic efficiency and consumer welfare to determine whether to deploy antitrust remedies), toward broader philosophical concerns over monopoly’s effects on democracy itself.

Her two most notable planks boil down to this:

“Companies with an annual global revenue of $25 billion or more and that offer to the public an online marketplace, an exchange, or a platform for connecting third parties would be designated as ‘platform utilities.’

“These companies would be prohibited from owning both the platform utility and any participants on that platform. Platform utilities would be required to meet a standard of fair, reasonable, and nondiscriminatory dealing with users. Platform utilities would not be allowed to transfer or share data with third parties.”

In other words, the rationale for the breakup of tech companies in part turns on “structural separation,” as journalist David Dayen explains, which means that companies like Amazon or Google “would not be allowed to both own the platform and also participate as a seller on that platform.” The idea behind this separation is that it prevents the companies from controlling content via control of distribution, which can create long-term competitive distortions, even though in the short term, consumers might benefit from the lower prices offered by a large-scale retailer like Amazon. This logic moves beyond book retailing: It is what gave America separation of ownership of movie studios and movie theaters before online streaming provided by Amazon and Netflix started taking over.

Regulators, argues the legal scholar Lina Khan, “cannot cognize the potential harms to competition posed by Amazon’s dominance if we measure competition primarily through price and output. Specifically, current doctrine [which largely is governed by consumer welfare considerations] underappreciates the risk of predatory pricing and how integration across distinct business lines may prove anticompetitive.”

Fair enough. But it may still be useful to make a distinction between platforms for advertising and selling commercial goods (e.g., Amazon) and platforms for publication/speech/information (e.g., Facebook and Twitter). In the case of the former, the business models of these platforms depend on as many clicks or purchases as possible—on size. The larger the better. Consequently, if a company like Amazon becomes too restrictive via predatory practices, it will begin to reduce the number of clicks and undermine the basis for its pricing model. This need for size means that there are some constraints on these platforms being able to favor their goods or listings over those of others but, as Khan and Warren would argue, probably not enough, which is why competition should be encouraged via antitrust.

The problem with social media platforms that are publication or speech vehicles is somewhat different, as we are seeing with increasing censorship of some voices or viewpoints. It is unclear whether breaking up Facebook, and having multiple competing platforms, actually solves the problem of, say, dissemination of “fake news.” FCC oversight and regulation would seem to be a better way of dealing with this issue.

While resisting calls to break up Amazon specifically, frustratingly, O’Rourke fails to specify any kind of distinction among the big tech giants and whether they should be subject to different remedies. Beyond expressing gratitude “for people who are talking about different ways to ensure that at a time of historic corporate concentration and vast disparity in wealth and income, that we look for ways to ensure that everybody can participate in the economy.” That’s the kind of vapid rhetoric that has characterized much of O’Rourke’s campaign so far, but he fails to put any meat and bones on his proposals to deal with the pathologies that he describes. For example, is there an inherent trade-off between corporate concentration and economic dynamism? If so, what is the right legislative/regulatory response?

One point of commonality between both candidates is their implicit support of small business. Warren suggests that increased competition levels the playing field between large and small businesses, which in turn helps to spur greater innovation. Likewise, O’Rourke advocates “that we try to encourage small business development and growth, which is suffering as a result of corporate concentration.”

Do their benign assumptions that both make about small businesses stand up to scrutiny? And to O’Rourke’s point specifically, in what way is business development suffering as a consequence as a result of corporation concentration?

To the first point, there is a significant body of research since the days of Joseph Schumpeter (the intellectual godfather of the economics of innovation) indicating that R&D spending and R&D productivity increase with scale. True, smaller firms have less bureaucracy and in theory can adapt their technology quicker to the needs of the marketplace. But a comprehensive examination of the empirical data by Professors Anne Marie Knott and Carl Vieregger at the University of Illinois leads to the following conclusion:

“Not only do large firms (using the US Small Business Association definition of greater than 500 employees) conduct 5.75 more R&D in aggregate than small firms, they have 13% higher productivity with that R&D. However this merely captures the private returns to their R&D. A further benefit of large firm R&D is that it generates the spillovers upon which small firm innovation free-rides.” (Emphasis added.)

The point about R&D would seem to offer support to O’Rourke’s drive to ensure dynamism in our economy, as does the idea that small firms get a “free-ride” as far as innovation goes. This is one concrete way to make sense of O’Rourke’s point on economic dynamism.

So as far as O’Rourke is concerned, companies like Amazon do not suffer from “the curse of bigness.” In fact, the myth of the plucky entrepreneur obscures the fact that in many instances smaller businesses are in reality the bad guys when it comes offering decent wages and a generous array of social benefits, such as health care provision or tolerance of unionization (the decimation of which has played a huge role behind the increase of wage inequality in our society). And even when they have had minimal levels of concentration, many small businesses are also marked by “low productivity levels, productivity growth rates hovering around zero, and low real wages,” according to an INET-supported study by Professors Lance Taylor and Özlem Ömer. As a result, small businesses are often the first to protest increased regulation or “burdensome” mandates, such as those for additional health care provision or increased unionization.

That hardly makes them ideal candidates for the kinds of things Warren is aiming to achieve with her proposals. To his credit, O’Rourke made the argument that “the Federal Trade Commission should place more intense scrutiny on smaller corporations that he characterized as being able to fly under the radar,” particularly in regard to some of their more abusive aspects in regard to poor benefits provision, meager wage gains, and hostility to unionization. But is the FTC the right body to rectify these abuses? Much of what O’Rourke criticizes would best be handled as a Department of Labor issue.

It is worth noting that one of Warren’s chief targets, Google, has just mandated “that all its temporary and contractor workers based in the United States receive a $15 minimum wage by 2020 and comprehensive healthcare, including eight sick days and 12 weeks of paid parental leave, by 2022,” according to a recent piece by Jillian D’Onfro for Forbes.com. This echoes a recent move by Amazon to raise minimum wages to $15 per hour.

To be clear, there are many disturbing practices worthy of elimination in both Google and Amazon (here and here). But it is also salient that both companies introduced the increased wages largely in response to mounting political pressure (Amazon explicitly acknowledged this), as opposed to waiting on legislation that would force the change. That provides some implicit support for the view that larger corporations generally have a greater economic capacity to enhance working conditions for their employees than smaller businesses (even if their motivations are to pre-empt even greater change that they strongly oppose), which would implicitly support O’Rourke’s arguments that size alone is not a good reason to break up these companies.

The point is that greed, as opposed to affordability, has driven the big tech companies’ business decisions.

But what is the right legislative response? Neither candidate really frames this beyond “break them up” or “size doesn’t matter.” Should we tackle the greed via vigorous antitrust enforcement or introduce labor legislation that facilitates unionization and shifts the power balance back somewhat toward labor? Historically, unionization has proven to be a much more effective route toward greater income equality, as unions proved more successful in mitigating the gap between labor productivity and wages. Sadly, neither Warren nor O’Rourke has much to say about unions.

What about the specific issue of size itself? From what we can see, O’Rourke seems to be more in favor of a size-neutral approach, whereas Warren’s proposals specifically cite a cut-off point of $25 billion in global revenues as a prima facie reason to break up the tech giants. According to Dayen:

“Warren’s campaign sees the $25 billion figure as a clean way to assist regulators with pinpointing market dominance. ‘It has the benefit of a clear rule,’ said one senior campaign adviser, who was not authorized to speak on the record. ‘We should presume if a company with over $25 billion in revenue is operating a marketplace, it has power and leverage.’”

But why should regulators make that sort of presumption in a globalized economy full of companies whose revenues vastly exceed that figure? Ford, GM, Toyota and countless other automobile manufacturers have global revenues well in excess of $25 billion. Seldom have we heard calls to break up Detroit’s “Big Three” despite global revenues in the hundreds of billions. Why? Because there is a widespread recognition that these companies are facing significant challenges in a global market dominated by similarly large competitors.

Likewise with some of the global food companies, such as Unilever or Nestle. Or consider the pet food industry, which is largely dominated by three suppliers. Should we be breaking up “Big Cat Food,” or is there something about a $25 billion global revenues metric that is intrinsic to big tech? By the same token, is it fair to make a presumption that businesses with much smaller revenues lack potentially abusive power and leverage?

No question, it is fair game for Dayen to highlight the “incestuous” linkages between some of the institutes and think tanks that are broadly supportive of big tech and oppose the Warren proposals (such as the American Enterprise Institute). After all, they serve as intellectual advocates for the business models of companies such as Google. By the same token, we suspect that they will find much to like about O’Rourke’s statements on Amazon. But beyond pointing out the potential conflicts of interest, it would be helpful to gain a better understanding of the global revenue metric beyond it simply having the virtue of clarity, if nothing else to find out whether Warren or O’Rourke is closer to a viable policy response.

In support of O’Rourke’s “size neutrality,” it is important to note that there is nothing in the economic literature on antitrust that would provide any kind of empirical gauge to assess whether there is something sacrosanct about a $25 billion figure. In that sense, the figure adopted by Warren evokes the arbitrary limits on debts and deficits established for fiscal sustainability rules in the European Monetary Union’s so-called “Stability and Growth Pact” (which also have the “virtue” of clarity, even though the rules themselves are devoid of economic common sense).

In the same piece, Dayen writes:

“Andy Kessler at the Wall Street Journal denied that antitrust law has anything to do with bigness.

“The idea that John Sherman, author of the Sherman Antitrust Act, was not concerned with bigness would come as news to Sherman, who once said, ‘If we will not endure a king as a political power, we should not endure a king over the production, transportation, and sale of any of the necessaries of life.’”

In truth, however, the Sherman Act was conceived by its eponymous author in large part to avert more radical measures, as was noted by William Letwin in his seminal analysis of the Sherman Act, Law and Economic Policy in America. Much as FDR conceived of the New Deal as rescue for capitalism rather than an embrace of socialism, Sherman introduced antitrust lest Congress pave the way “for the socialist, the communist, and the nihilist.” In the words of antitrust law Professor Daniel Crane: “From the Sherman Act forward… it is certain that antitrust has often been deployed as a foil to more interventionist forms of regulation. The ideological and political implications of that move are complex and not neatly housed in right/left categories.” Sherman and his fellow trust-busters (such as the Roosevelts) may have been unwilling to “endure a king” over production, transportation, etc., but they were certainly willing to tolerate a number of archdukes. Likewise, it seems would Beto O’Rourke.

And here we come to the tension inherent in Warren’s antitrust proposals. Is the ultimate goal to break up these companies in order to foster greater market competition? If so, to what end, or is it simply enough to let markets be markets, even if market forces lend themselves precisely to the kinds of pathologies that Warren is seeking to eliminate?

Both Warren and O’Rourke admirably pay heed to the less fortunate via cash transfers from winners to losers with increased public provision. But they fail to consider whether the deregulated labor and goods markets that are hallmarks of today’s antitrust propositions actually exacerbate the problems that create those vulnerabilities in the first place.

Likewise, in regard to the issue of data security, and data privacy, antitrust might not offer the best solution. The EU framework for data protection, or the California Consumer Privacy Act, has the makings of an early-stage template for consumer protections on these issues (although in the case of Facebook, this may be a case of closing the barn door after the horse has bolted, given that American Facebook users are abandoning it by the millions, the company’s “original sharing” is rapidly declining, and its WhatsApp subsidiary, the takeover of which Warren seeks to unwind, is rapidly being superseded in quality by China’s WeChat).

But what about the idea that we should all be thankful “now [that] we have the option of using Google instead of being stuck with Bing,” as Warren herself queries in support of increasing competition among search engines? Network theory, as I’ve written before, leads to a different kind of assessment, because the value of a search engine expands as an increasing number of other users use it, thereby enhancing its value to the user. (That would seem to support O’Rourke’s criticism of Warren’s “break ’em up” ideology, although he does not specifically cite economic network theory as explicit support for economic dynamism.) The corollary also applies insofar as the benefits of a search engine diminish as the number of users decreases, as more search engines are created (and recall the earlier point about innovation and size, which suggests that more competitive choice does not necessarily mean that a better mousetrap is created). Given that these businesses have reached levels of sophistication and capacity, as well as unique periods of benign growth and talent agglomeration, they can’t be easily replicated, so breaking them up via early 20th-century instruments, such as the Sherman Act, might not solve the problem.

If there is something inherent about network effects whereby online social networks like Facebook or search engines such as Google lend themselves to becoming natural monopolies, then the answer might be to regulate them as utilities, rather than breaking them up, as no less a figure than right-wing populist Steve Bannon has suggested. The advantage of the utility model of regulation is that it removes the determination of wages and prices of necessities from either markets or direct state control and put them in the more neutral realm of state-brokered bargaining (an approach earlier championed by both trust-buster Theodore Roosevelt and New Dealer Franklin D. Roosevelt).

Finally, it has to be asked whether it is wise to formulate antitrust policy on the basis of specific domestic requirements, while ignoring the challenges posed by global state-subsidized Chinese national champions: companies such as WeChat, Huawei, Alibaba or Baidu. At a minimum, the global challenge posed by China’s national champions gives some legitimacy to O’Rourke’s hesitation as far as breaking up companies such as Amazon.

Well-crafted industrial policy is the kind of thing the American economy used to do rather well in fact before the deregulatory zeal of the Chicago School maligned any kind of national development strategies as something akin to rent-seeking crony capitalism. As a general rule, the more one uses antitrust to produce increasing domestic competition and less large companies, the more we may have to close the domestic market to international competition and provide export subsidies in order to compete globally. That won’t fly under the World Trade Organization, but without national protectionism and an assertive geo-economic strategy, the more costly becomes the application of antitrust rules based on national considerations alone.

Beyond that, it is worth pondering whether the big tech behemoths are a product or a cause of our current democratic dysfunction. If you listen to O’Rourke, big tech is symptomatic of our economic dynamism, as opposed to dysfunction. From Warren’s perspective, it is a pollutant on U.S. democracy. But neither considers whether the earlier existence of progressive tripartite-type deals amid an industrial backdrop of big companies, big unions and big government would be a workable model today.

Unfortunately, in her efforts to act as a cheerleader for capitalism and market competition via aggressive antitrust remedies, Warren ignores other remedies of the kind embodied in the Treaty of Detroit. And her antitrust proposals acknowledge no role for possible utility-style regulation (ironically, that is coming from the populist right). As far as O’Rourke goes, in typical Beto fashion, he doesn’t actually give a precise indication of what he thinks we should do. Beyond his vague idea that Amazon is a symbol of our economic dynamism, his call to leave the company alone sounds more like a device to help distinguish him in an increasingly crowded pack of contenders (and maybe a chance to source additional funding from Silicon Valley), rather than a serious policy proposal.

The problems O’Rourke and Warren define are real, but neither candidate has yet developed credible problems to the pathologies described in our current economy. We should be happy that we at least have the start of a serious debate on the subject, but let’s hope that the Democrats can improve on the current menu of options.


By Marshall Auerback

MORE FROM Marshall Auerback


Related Topics ------------------------------------------

All Salon Beto O'rourke Big Tech Elizabeth Warren Independent Media Institute News & Politics Tech Giants